Author Eoin O’Shea
Criminal liability and the politics of
enforcement
The UK is debating whether to reform criminal law in order to widen the liability
of corporate bodies for a wide category of “economic crimes”. If implemented,
companies would be vicariously liable if they failed to prevent such crimes by their
agents, including directors, employees, subsidiaries and intermediaries, and the law
would have far-reaching effects on business life.
INTRODUCTION
n
Individuals usually have minds of their
own. A working assumption is that
an adult is responsible for his own voluntary
conduct. Another working assumption is that
the individual’s voluntary conduct usually
demonstrates their state of mind.
Corporate bodies are obviously
different.
As collections of contracted
individuals, assets and legal rights,
companies are essentially creations of law,
without a single unified state of mind. It
can be very difficult to identify a particular
intention held by a corporate entity at a
particular point in time. They can only act
through individual agents.
Nevertheless
companies are “legal persons”, separate
entities from any agent or shareholder.
COMPANIES AND CRIME
This presents a problem for the criminal law.
Almost all serious crime involves a mental
element. The state of mind of the accused is
what distinguishes borrowing from theft or a
gift from a bribe.
In seeking a theory by which companies
can be liable for acts of their agents, English
law has developed the “directing mind” test,
also known as the identification doctrine.1
The doctrine is that where a person acts “as”
the company, ie where his or her mind is the
“directing mind and will” of the company, then
his state of knowledge and state of mind can
be attributed to the company and the company
can be liable for his actions and defaults.
The classic expression of the
identification principle is the case of
Tesco v Nattrass.2 In that case the errors
of a supermarket store-manager were not
attributable to the company, because the
manager was not acting as the “directing
mind” of the company as a whole. He was
not a delegate to which the company had
passed its responsibilities.
Although the binding effect of Tesco has
been debated in some depth,3 it is clear that
the directing mind test remains at least the
starting point for analysis of corporate criminal
liability for crimes requiring a mental element.4
Where Parliament has sought to impose
criminal liability on companies it has done
so in a piecemeal fashion, for example in the
field of health and safety at work or corporate
manslaughter.5 Bribery is a special case which
we will come on to later.
So the default position in England is that
companies cannot commit crimes requiring
a guilty mind, unless someone senior enough
in the company can be proven to have the
relevant mental state.
This reflects a (usually)
unspoken assumption of English law that a
company is not obliged to police employee
conduct which is unauthorised. The company
is not its employees’ keeper, if the employee is
on a frolic of his own.
The US example?
We can contrast the English position
with that in the US. In US federal law, a
corporation is vicariously criminally liable
for the illegal acts of any of its employees
or other agents if the employee was acting
within the scope of their employment and
their actions were intended, at least in part,
Butterworths Journal of International Banking and Financial Law
to benefit the corporation.
The principle is
accorded the Latin tag respondeat superior
(“let the master answer”). It reflects a
different assumption about the duty
of employers to police the behaviour of
employees, whether authorised or not.
Prosecutions against corporations are far
more common in the US than in the UK and
the phenomenon has not gone un-noticed by
campaigners against corporate misfeasance or
indeed by UK law-enforcement agencies. The
latter believe that reform of corporate liability
is an important step towards more effective
enforcement action against white-collar crime.
The model proposed is an extension
or adaptation of s 7 of the Bribery
Act 2010.
The proposal was originally
championed by the Attorney-General, 6
though subsequent reports have suggested
less enthusiasm by the Conservative
Government, at least partly on the ground
that there were no prosecutions under the
Bribery Act at that point.7
However, in late 2015 the first
settlement of a s 7 bribery case was
approved by the English courts, being
resolved by means of a deferred prosecution
agreement involving penalties of more than
US$33m. 8 In a separate case, a company
has entered a guilty plea and will be
sentenced later this year.9 Therefore, the
Bribery Act is starting to develop a track
record. Moreover the concept of vicarious
liability has gained acceptance and there
seems no prospect of the UK changing the
principle, at least as regards bribery.
The Director of the Serious Fraud Office,
David Green QC, has been a champion of
extending the Bribery Act to all economic
crime for quite some time.
He is likely to be
re-appointed to his position later this year.
He has continued his campaign for vicarious
liability in speeches and in the media, and
the reform has long been supported by other
(2016) 2 JIBFL 103A
February 2016
CRIMINAL LIABILITY AND THE POLITICS OF ENFORCEMENT
Feature
KEY POINTS
Any
–– legislation expanding corporate criminal liability should only apply to specific
offences (capable of being amended in the future).
The
–– potential effect of widening the UK’s criminal jurisdiction extraterritorially merits
very considerable thought.
Businesses would have to invest considerably more resources into their legal and
––
regulatory functions.
1
. CRIMINAL LIABILITY AND THE POLITICS OF ENFORCEMENT
Feature
political parties. Mr Green’s advocacy, and
the recent successful prosecutions under the
Bribery Act, have moved the issue of reform
back into the limelight.
The very recent acqittal of six brokers on
charges connected with LIBOR manipulation
has been spun as a setback for the SFO.
However the agency’s supporters would claim
such reverses strengthen the case for reform
generally.
The Bribery Act as a model?
Section 7 of the Bribery Act circumvented
the identity principle for corporate
criminal liability by creating a specific
offence of failing to prevent bribery by
others. The offence can only be committed
by commercial organisations (essentially
companies and partnerships) and only
applies if a person acting for or on behalf
of the organisation pays a bribe in order
to obtain or retain business or a business
advantage for the organisation. There is
no requirement of negligence on the part
of senior management or anyone else and
the offence is very close to the US rule of
vicarious liability.
However, the company
has a defence if it can prove that it had
“adequate procedures” designed to prevent
the payment of bribes by associated persons
– effectively a due-diligence defence.
Definition of offences
If the SFO persuaded the government to extend
the Bribery model to other “economic” crimes
then what would the new regime look like?
Defining “economic crime” would be
critical. The obvious candidates for inclusion
would include bribery, fraud, insider-dealing
and false accounting.
Other candidates may not be as
straightforward. For example, operating a
cartel is a paradigm example of an economic
crime, that is, an activity criminalised because
of its wider economic effects.
However there
is already a detailed regime designed to
prevent cartels and anti-competitive conduct
generally. Although the criminalisation of
cartels has not been seen as successful so far,
recent reform of the law has taken place and
there is already a specialised agency charged
with regulating cartel activity.
2
February 2016
Money-laundering is also an
economic crime par excellence but it
too is subject to an existing and highly
complex10 legal regime. Individuals (and
companies11) already face strict liability
for any involvement in suspected moneylaundering.
This is subject to a disclosure
defence and is, arguably, more draconian
than the failure to prevent the offence
which is being proposed.
It may be that the best way
to address these issues is for any
legislation to apply only to a specific
list of relevant offences which would be
capable of being amended in the future,
rather than effect a complete re-casting
of corporate liability.
Extended jurisdiction?
Jurisdiction will also be a tricky issue. The
default position is that UK criminal law
is territorial in effect. Only if acts relevant
to the crime occur in the UK will the UK
have jurisdiction.
However, another of the innovations
of the Bribery Act was to create a very
wide, extra-territorial jurisdiction in
relation to bribery offences, in particular
under s 7.
The proposal to model the
new offence on s 7 of the Bribery Act
would bring these extended jurisdictional
provisions with it. The potential effect of
widening the UK’s criminal jurisdiction
in this way merits very considerable
thought. Do the British authorities really
want the ability to prosecute crimes all
round the world which have little or no
connection with Britain save that the
company potentially responsible happens
to have a sales office in London?
Anti-crime compliance
procedures?
The Bribery Act model carries with it a
defence to the effect that a company may
avoid vicarious liability if it can show it had
adequate procedures designed to prevent the
wrongdoing in question.
It is too early to say
what an acceptable anti-crime due-diligence
programme might look like. But we can
make an educated guess that, because of
the much wider scope of liability, it would
(2016) 2 JIBFL 103A
have to be considerably more involved and
complex than the ABAC (anti-bribery and
corruption) procedures which are now
common in business.
If the bribery model is followed, a simple
instruction to abide by the criminal law would
not suffice. There would have to be riskassessments, studies, surveys, board meetings
and policy documents, not to mention more
compliance professionals to keep the system
running.
Corporate employees may look
forward to considerable time spent in training
sessions on various forms of villainy of which
they might previously have been ignorant.
Other effects of the reform
Extending the s 7 model to other economic
crime may have much wider effects on
corporate life and culture.
Businesses would have to invest
considerably more resources into their legal
and regulatory functions. The role of General
Counsel, traditionally less prominent in the
UK than in the US, would grow considerably.
The resources available to the SFO and
other law-enforcement agencies dealing with
economic crime would also have to grow.
Much as has happened in relation to bribery,
a mini-industry of compliance, advisory,
consulting and training experts would
develop. Corporate decision-making would
probably become more risk-averse but also,
perhaps more deliberative.
The merits of reform
Whether one sees such changes as positive
or negative turns ultimately on deeper views
about business, economics and society.
David
Green believes the change is necessary in order
to fulfil public expectations.12 There is clearly
a perception that bad actors in the City and
elsewhere have not felt the full force of the law
(despite record penalties having been imposed
by regulators such as the FCA). There is also
a perception that US prosecutors are more
effective in holding corporations to account,
due in part to the effect of vicarious liability.
These are powerful arguments.
Companies do have a responsibility to
discourage wrongdoing by those acting
on their behalves, especially when the
misconduct is facilitated (wittingly or not)
Butterworths Journal of International Banking and Financial Law
. by the individual miscreant having access to
the company’s resources. Accountability is in
the long-term interests of management and
investors alike. At present, blind eyes can be
turned too easily and too often.
Nevertheless, there is something to be
said for the general principle that culpability
should depend on voluntariness, and
vicarious liability should be an exception
rather than a rule. It would be unfortunate
if a side-effect of corporate criminal liability
was an over-legalistic approach to every
issue or making companies so intrusive
and controlling that they stifle individual
responsibility and risk-taking.
More pragmatic considerations may
ultimately decide the fate of these proposals.
Unfortunately, the prestige of the SFO tends
to ebb and flow according to the results of
high profile cases and it is impossible to
predict its influence on government policy
in future.
But politics and economics are
never far from the minds of those who will
consider the case for reform. Further financial
scandals or business failings in the next years
may galvanise legislators and have more of
an effect on the nature of corporate criminal
liability than the arguments of prosecutors or
commentators ever could.
n
1 Like so much of company law, the principle
was first developed in the civil context, see for
example, Lennard’s Carrying Co Ltd v Asiatic
Petroleum Co Ltd [1915] A.C.
705.
2 [1972] A.C. 153.
3 For example Meridian Global Funds
Management Asia v Securities Commission
[1995] 2 AC 500.
4 See, for example, the current guidance for
crown prosecutors issued by the Crown
Prosecution Service www.cps.gov.uk/legal/
5 Corporate Manslaughter and Corporate
Homicide Act 1997, Health & Safety at
Work Act 1974.
6 Financial Times, 2 September 2014.
7 http://www.lawgazette.co.uk/news/
government-drops-plan-to-extend-corporatecriminal-liability/5051277.fullarticle
8 Serious Fraud Office v Standard Bank,
Southwark Crown Court 30 November 2015,
https://www.judiciary.gov.uk/judgments/
serious-fraud-office-v-standard-bank/
Butterworths Journal of International Banking and Financial Law
9 http://www.sfo.gov.uk/press-room/latestpress-releases/press-releases-2015/sweettgroup-plc-pleads-guilty-to-bribery-offence.
aspx.
10 Proceeds of Crime Act 2001, Pt 7. The
legislation and the disclosure/enforcement
regimes are far from satisfactory, especially in
the context of corporate offending, however
the proposed reform is most unlikely to
change this.
11 Albeit subject to the identification test.
12 “Fraud chief calls for tougher corporate
prosecution laws”, London Evening Standard,
6 January 2016.
CRIMINAL LIABILITY AND THE POLITICS OF ENFORCEMENT
Feature
Biog box
Eoin O’Shea is a partner at Reed Smith.
Eoin’s practice focuses on corporate crime,
in particular the law of bribery and corruption, money-laundering and fraud. Eoin is
experienced in managing internal investigations, criminal and civil fraud matters side by
side. He also acts for senior individuals under investigation for financial crime.
Eoin is
dual-qualified as a barrister and solicitor. He was called to the Bar of England and Wales in
1996 and is also a member of the Irish Bar. He is the author of the leading textbook on the
UK Bribery Act.
Email: eoshea@reedsmith.com
Further Reading:
The
–– Financial Conduct Authority
continues to explore bribery and corruption risks in regulated firms [2015]
4 JIBFL 226.
The
–– extraterritorial reach of criminal
and enforcement action in the English
courts [2014] 1 JIBFL 47.
LexisPSL: Corporate Crime: Bribery
––
and corruption – 2015 in review.
(2016) 2 JIBFL 103A
February 2016
3
.