1) Two steps forward, one step back
The proposed amendments to China’s Anti-Unfair Competition Law
by Qing Lyu, Jiaming Zhang and Adrian Emch*
On 25 February 2016, the Legislative Affairs Office of the State
Council – China’s “cabinet” – published a draft (the Draft) of the
proposed amendments to the Anti-Unfair Competition Law
(AUCL) and invited comments by stakeholders.
Draft in a nutshell
The AUCL contains a potpourri of provisions aimed at protecting
fair competition, and covering legal fields such as intellectual
property and commercial bribery, as well as antitrust. It was enacted
in 1993, at the initial stages of China’s economic reform under
Deng Xiaoping. After more than 20 years of implementation, the
market practice has evolved and new rules – for example, the
Trademark Law and the Anti-Monopoly Law (AML) – have been
enacted to regulate the areas covered in the AUCL.
The Draft proposes an important overhaul of the current law,
especially in the fields of antitrust, intellectual property and antibribery. It aims to bring the AUCL more in line with recent
domestic legislation and more in sync with international legal
standards, and to codify existing case law and practice.
The proposed AUCL amendments have implications far
beyond the antitrust arena. For instance, in the IP field, the Draft
improves the AUCL’s protection over those rights that cannot
benefit from registration with the authorities, such as unregistered
marks, trade dress, product packaging and trade secrets.
In the anti-bribery field, the Draft brings the Chinese antibribery laws into line with well-recognised international standards.
For example, while the AUCL currently prohibits bribe payments
made in order to “sell or purchase products,” the Draft expands the
definition of “commercial bribery” to conduct whereby
“economic advantages” are provided or promised to third parties,
in order to secure opportunities or competitive advantages.
In the antitrust arena, the Draft also promises to bring
substantial changes, as set out below.
Alignment with the AML
As mentioned, the AUCL was enacted long before the enactment
in 2007 of the AML, which is generally more in line with up-todate international antitrust practices. It is against this background
that the Draft proposes to delete a few antitrust provisions from the
AUCL to avoid overlap and inconsistency with the AML.
In particular, while there are subtle textual differences between
the two laws, both the AUCL and the AML ban predatory
pricing, tying and the imposition of unreasonable transaction
conditions. But unlike the AML, the AUCL does not require
demonstration that the company at issue has a dominant position
for such types of conduct to be illegal. Hence, at this point in time,
predatory pricing, tying and the imposition of unreasonable
conditions can be illegal under the AUCL for any company,
irrespective of its market position. By deleting the AUCL
provisions, the Draft proposes to give the AML’s text full meaning
as the only applicable legal framework for these types of conduct.
The AUCL also singles out public utilities and other
monopolies – mainly state-owned enterprises – by prohibiting
them from engaging in exclusive dealing and tying. The
background of this prohibition is that, back in 1993, the radical
transformation of the Chinese economy within the framework
of Deng Xiaoping’s “reform and opening-up policy” was going
ahead full steam. At that moment in China’s reform process, the
economy was largely dominated by state-owned companies, and
specific regulation of their behaviour seemed appropriate.
In today’s China, private enterprises play a much more
important role than in 1993, and the legislator today may feel
that it is no longer necessary to single out public utilities and
state monopolies, as the AML should apply to companies
irrespective of their ownership. As a result, the Draft also
proposes to delete this provision from the AUCL.
Another set of overlapping provisions between the AUCL
and the AML is in the area of “administrative monopoly”
conduct, a term used in China to describe government’s anticompetitive interference in the marketplace.
The current AUCL has a relatively high-level provision banning
government bodies and assimilated agencies from abusing
administrative powers to restrict competition, such as appointing
exclusive suppliers or discriminating against non-local companies.
In turn, the AML contains an entire chapter on administrative
monopoly, outlawing specific manifestations in quite some detail.
As with the other above-mentioned provisions, the Draft resolves
the discrepancies across laws by proposing to delete the AUCL
provision on administrative monopoly, leaving the field to the
more specialised provisions of the AML.
Overall, therefore, the Draft’s deletions cut overlaps, ensure
a higher degree of consistency between the AUCL and AML
provisions and may thereby reduce uncertainty for businesses.
“Relatively advantageous position”
While the above deletions may bring more comfort to market
players, article 6 of the Draft goes in the opposite direction.
Essentially, article 6 attempts to address situations where a
company is not dominant, but has a “relatively advantageous
position” vis-a-vis counterparties in the course of trade, and
engages in certain activities deemed anticompetitive or unfair.
The threshold for the relatively advantageous position is clearly
meant to be lower than that of “dominance.” The Draft proposes
to look at factors such as financial strength, technology, market
access, sales channel or raw materials procurement to check if
they create a relationship of dependence on the company by its
trading partners. If so, the company may be deemed to have a
relatively advantageous position.
Similar to the AML’s abuse of dominance rules, the Draft
does not prohibit companies from having or obtaining a
relatively advantageous position as such. Only certain abuses
of such position can be illegal.
* Hogan Lovells International LLP (Beijing)
8
10 May 2016 • Competition Law Insight
2) Two steps forward, one step back
According to article 6, an abuse may take the shape of (for
example) restrictions on the trading partners’ business dealings
with third parties; exclusive purchasing; abusive charges on (or
requiring unreasonable economic benefits from) trading
partners; or the imposition of unreasonable conditions.
The “relatively advantageous position” concept is fairly –
though not completely – new in China. In the past, there were
a limited number of similar rules in other pieces of legislation.
In particular, in 2006, the Chinese antitrust authorities – the
Ministry of Commerce, the National Development and Reform
Commission, and the State Administration for Industry and
Commerce – and two other ministries jointly issued the
Administrative Measures for Fair Transactions between Retailers
and Suppliers. These measures aim to regulate the relationship
between retailers – basically, large shops, supermarkets and chain
stores – and individual suppliers. They contain a broad range of
rules including the prohibition of unfair transaction practices by
retailers vis-a-vis their suppliers by “abusing an advantageous
position”. In Wumei v Lifeng, a court applied this prohibition,
holding that a big supermarket chain abused such an advantageous
position by forcing “unconditional rebates” on its supplier.
Internationally, China is not completely isolated with the
proposed relatively advantageous position draft: Germany,
Japan and Korea have similar rules. In fact, article 6 in the
proposed AUCL amendment draws heavily on German – and
to a lesser extent – Japanese and Korean competition laws.
From an enforcement perspective, the experience in these
jurisdictions suggests that proving a relatively advantageous
position (or similar concept) is often easier than proving a
dominant position. Broadly speaking, the former often only
requires a comparison between the relative positions of the
trading parties involved, while the latter typically demands an
overall market assessment.
Among the jurisdictions with rules similar to the Chinese
relatively advantageous position concept, some enforce the rules
more actively than others – for example, in Korea, the Korean
Fair Trade Commission (KFTC) reportedly prosecuted over
3,000 cases from 1981 to 2014. The 2007 Posco judgment by the
Supreme Court, overturning a KFTC abuse of dominance
decision, may have led to a further shift of focus on abuse of
“superior position” cases with their relatively lighter burden of
proof (as opposed to abuse of dominance cases).
If the Draft’s proposals remain in the final amendment of the
AUCL and are enforced vigorously in practice, the impact of
article 6 on companies doing business in or with China could be
far-reaching. While the relatively advantageous position concept
may potentially be beneficial to small(er) companies, it risks
creating a new level of rather opaque compliance obligations on
larger companies. Moreover, the penalties for breaching article 6
can be high. The Draft provides for fines of up to five times the
“illegal revenues,” a concept not explained in the Draft. If those
revenues cannot be determined, a statutory fine ranging between
RMB100,000 and RMB3m can be imposed.
Unfair competition in the internet sector
Other antitrust reforms can be found in the Draft’s new rules on
unfair competition between internet companies.
Over the past few years, many of China’s largest internet and
ecommerce companies were entangled in legal disputes with
Competition Law Insight • 10 May 2016
each other. Most of these disputes were channelled through
the Chinese court system. The disputes involved new types of
unfair competition conduct such as adblocking; enabling users
free access to others’ non-free content; and inducing users of
other products to use one’s own products.
Given the lack of specific rules on internet-based conduct in
the AUCL, the Chinese courts dealt with these cases on the
basis of article 2 of the AUCL, a provision referring to highlevel principles such as voluntariness, equality, fairness,
honesty and good faith. From these principles, the courts
developed other, more concrete principles – such as “noninterference” with the legitimate operations of competitors –
though the case law is uneven across different courts in China.
Now the Draft attempts to codify some of the existing case
law on unfair competition in the internet arena – drawing on
the courts’ experience from (among others) the Qihoo 360 v
Tencent and Tencent v Sogou cases – by inserting a specific
provision applicable to internet disputes.
In particular, article 13 of the Draft incorporates the noninterference principle into the AUCL, prohibiting companies
from “interfering” with users’ options or other companies’
normal business operations by using network technology or
app services. Without prior consent, companies are prohibited
from using technical methods to stop users from using other
companies’ online services; inserting links in others’ online
services to force skipping to targeted content; misleading,
cheating or forcing users to revise, close, uninstall or stop the
normal use of online services legally provided by others; or
interfering with, or destroying, the regular operations of
online services legally provided by others.
In general, the insertion of article 13 is an understandable
attempt to make sure the rules are applied consistently among
courts and authorities. At the same time, the internet industry is a
vibrant sector with fast-moving technologies and business practices
and the provision in the Draft risks becoming outdated quickly.
Conclusions
The Draft may be seen as an attempt by the Chinese government
to modernise Chinese unfair competition rules. If the proposals in
the Draft are enacted, the AUCL’s rules would be brought more
in line with other Chinese legal texts, such as the Trademark Law
or the AML, and – to an extent – international practices.
From an antitrust perspective, seeking to align the AUCL and
the AML is surely laudable, and the abrogation of prohibitions of
predatory pricing, tying and imposition of unreasonable
conditions by companies irrespective of their market position
appears to make sense. At the same time, the introduction of the
new concept of a “relatively advantageous position” may add
significant compliance obligations for companies and hence risks
significantly reducing the benefits of the AUCL reform.
The new provision on unfair competition conduct in the
internet space provides the benefit of codifying – and thus
streamlining – existing case law, but its static nature may freeze
developments at a particular moment in time.
Looking ahead, the State Council has already collected
stakeholder feedback on the Draft. As a next step, the Draft may
either be further amended (and potentially circulated for
comment again) or be directly sent to the Standing Committee
of the National People’s Congress for enactment.
9